Essay/Term paper: Broadcasting and programing
Essay, term paper, research paper: Management
Free essays available online are good but they will not follow the guidelines of your particular writing assignment. If you need a custom term paper on Management: Broadcasting And Programing, you can hire a professional writer here to write you a high quality authentic essay. While free essays can be traced by Turnitin (plagiarism detection program), our custom written essays will pass any plagiarism test. Our writing service will save you time and grade.
Broadcasting and Programing
Steiner's Model
Steiner's model on programming preferences and broadcasting choices tries to
show how stations come to the conclusion of what programming to show. This model
goes on the assumption that broadcasters will go after the largest audience
possible.
Going on the information given about this hypothetical situation, we can predict
what each of the four stations in this market will show.
There are three distinct audience preferences. The first groups of 1200 viewers
has a first programming preference of sitcoms and a second choice of soaps. The
second group numbers 900 viewers and would pick cops first and soaps second. The
third group, 500 viewers, likes soaps first and sitcoms and their second choice.
This model says that the audience will watch their first choice first and then
the second choice, but only is their first choice is not available.
Let's say that the Federal Communications Commission licenses station A in their
market. Looking at the viewer preferences, station A would start to broadcast
soaps. By show soaps, it would capture a market of 2600 viewers. All viewers
would watch because soaps is their first choice or it is their second choice but
their first is not available.
The FCC then offers a license to station B. After examining the audience sizes,
stations B also starts to show soaps. By programming to this audience, it splits
the soaps market with station A and both of them have 1300 viewers.
Station B does not pick another programming because no other choice can offer
more than 1300 viewers.
When the FCC offers a license to station C, things will definitely change in
this market. Station C sees the biggest audience available is the sitcom market
with 1200 viewers.
But when station C takes that 1200 viewers from the soap audience which hold
sitcoms as their first choice, station A and B will both drop to 700 viewers.
They now have to make a decision. Both can find larger markets elsewhere.
One station, and it does not matter which one, will switch to cop shows. For
this hypothetical, station B would choose cops for 900 viewers.
Station A, who still is showing soaps, now only has 500 viewers. It does not
like that, so it starts to show sitcoms. Audience 3, with 500 viewers, now is
watching sitcoms because there are no soaps out there. Station A and C are both
showing sitcoms and are splitting a viewer audience of 1700 for 850 each.
Now that the viewers are confused about what station is showing what, the FCC
offers a fourth license to station D. After examination, station D decides to
start broadcasting sitcoms in competition with stations A and C. All three
stations have an audience share of 566. That is more than the 500 soap viewers
or splitting the 900 cops viewers with station B.
Although Steiner's model is not too far off what happens in today's television
landscape, it does have a couple of drawbacks that keeps it from being a true
model.
Steiner does not take into consideration that some audiences are more valuable
to advertisers than others. Because advertisers want certain viewers, stations
might program to that audience to attract more advertising dollars.
Steiner also assumes that as stations go into competition with another station,
they will split the audience equally. That is not always the case. Viewers will
watch the station they believe has the better quality, even if there are two or
three stations showing the same thing.
This model does offer some insights on how stations and networks make decisions.
Just look at the TV Guide and see how many sitcoms there are on any given night.
This also shows why some minority viewers never get programming directed at them.
The stations are going to the majority audiences which have larger numbers. The
minority viewer preferences, under these model, have to have another station
before they get to see their shows, in this situation.
First Copy Costs
First copy costs in the newspaper industry are the fixed costs of owning a paper
and printing the first one.
First copy costs include the money spend on items that are necessary for the
newspaper to be printed. These fixed costs do not vary as the number of papers
increases or decreases. Because they do not vary, they are very important and
must be covered by advertising and subscriptions.
These fixed costs include the physical plant, the presses, the pressmen,
reporters, photographers, other staff members and the delivery trucks.
The interesting things about fixed costs is that you have to have them. You can
not scrimp or just not buy them. To cut corners, a paper does not hire reporters,
but how does it cover the local news? Whether or not you print a paper, you
still must pay for that stuff.
To figure the first copy costs of a newspaper, the fixed costs and the cost of
the paper and ink of the first issue off the press are added together. For
instance, let's say that the fixed costs of a newspaper is $1 million and the
first issue costs $1 to print. The first copy costs $1,000,001.
Looking at this, it sounds like newspapers would never make any money, but we
have not figured in variable costs. These include the paper, ink and related
costs of running the press. As the quantity of papers goes up, these prices
usually go down. As the quantity continues to go up, the average cost comes down
and each paper gets cheaper and cheaper.
First copy costs keep many papers from owning their own presses. Large dailies
must own their own presses in order to meet distribution deadlines and ensure
that their paper gets printed on time. Smaller papers can not afford that first
copy cost, so they have to contract with other to print their paper.
First copy costs are a determining factor in how a paper is operated. Whether it
owns it own presses or not, the size of its staff and how often it prints is all
tied into these first copy costs.
Economy of Scale with Cable TV
By the nature of the beast, cable operators normally get exclusive franchises to
supply a community with their cable service; so talking about competition in the
cable industry sounds like an oxymoron. But there are signs that it might
actually compete in a way.
Less than 50 cities in the United States are overbuilt, or have more than one
cable provider. Yet studies show that those overbuilt cities have lower basic
cable subscription rates, $14.31 compared to $17.31.
Can competition within the cable system be created?
Probably not. The barriers against entry for new cable operators in a specific
market are great.
To begin with, the new operator must get a franchise agreement with that city.
The incumbent franchise will not stand still for this. Those in the local
government also will fear that the incumbent franchise might change benefits or
disturb the local political situation.
Economics of Scale would suggest that the incumbent would have lower average
costs because they are already there and have a better distribution system. The
second franchise would have high entry costs because they have to string their
own cable and many times they have to bury the new cable. This additional work
means high construction costs and community aggravation as they tear up roads
and yards.
The incumbent can employ delay tactics to make it very hard to start up new
franchises. From political pressure to lawsuits to dropping price and keeping
their customers happy, delays will make the new guy on the block discouraged and
out.
Within the cable operator networks, like TCI or CableVision, networks themselves
own or have a financial interest in some of the channels they carry. Time-Warner
owns TBS, CNN and a host of other channels started by the Turner Broadcast
System.
Although this sounds like a serious violation of the anti-trust laws, no contest
has been put up against this practice. In fact, it has been shown that multi-
system operators and overbuilt cities' operators are more likely to provide
channels owned by other networks.
Carrying their own channels allows networks to increase profits and helps keep
subscription rates down. And, as a practical matter, cable systems need channels
to put out there for people to watch. Owning or having financial interest in
channels ensures that they have programming to carry.
With all the things going against the competition of cable systems, the market
demand for cable is elastic. The Crandall study, sponsored by TCI, showed that
an elastic rate of 2.2 means that as subscription rates go up 1 percent, 2.2
percent of the subscribers will cancel their service.
As the market show elasticity, the reality is that is normally does not work
that way. To persuade subscribers to take their higher rates, cable operators
offer new channels along with the rate hike. The number of channels has
traditionally been a measure of quality and as "quality" goes up, so can the
rates.
Cable in the near future will see some competition from sectors outside of the
cable industry. The Telecommunication Act of 1996 will make it easier for
telephone and utility companies to go head to head with the cable operators.
This might change the competition landscape of cable TV.
Programming to the Minority Audiences
Because networks and broadcasters look to capture the largest audience possible,
many times the minority tastes are ignored. These minorities now have more
choices today than they did before as technology expands.
Steiner's model described how broadcasters went after larger audiences and skip
over minority tastes. As technology advances and more stations are introduced,
Steiner's model would suggest that those minority tastes were met.
In a situation where government regulates a small number of broadcast stations,
minority taste audiences have little recourse. The only option that they have is
to petition the government to force the stations to program to them. Such was
the case with religious groups. They got the Federal Communications Commission
to make stations allocate time for specific religions and their shows.
In a government sponsored market with a limited number of channels, some
programming for the minority tastes will appear. The government would sponsor a
channel that showed minority taste programming. On the down side here, the other
broadcasters will continue to ignore minority tastes because their needs are met
somewhere else. Broadcasters will continue to aim for the majority markets.
Today, with an unlimited number of channels available, minorities have
programming provided to them. Those with minority tastes can now start their own
channel to cater strictly to themselves. Whatever their tastes, they will have
it.
The benefit of unlimited channel supply is that the market audience keeps
getting more and more programming. Once someone see a type of programming work
and make money, they might go after the same market. Broadcasters who once avoid
that type of programming can now start another channel and tap into that market
without detracting from its majority audience programming.
As the technology improves and allows more and more minority groups to get
involved with broadcasting, we will start to see a sharp increase in specialty
channels; more than what we currently see.